The Structure of Private and Commercial Auto Liability
Denyse Lemaire, Ph.D.
Cheyney University
Pierre Lemaire, Doctoral Student
Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania
I. Introduction
Traditional economic theory dictates that concentration facilitates collusion between firms and increases industry profitability. As the number of firms in a market increases, so does competition. An increase in competition, in turn, may lead to a decrease in price and therefore to decrease profits. This paper provides an analysis of private and commercial auto liability insurance using a market concentration framework. Three measures are used to compute market concentration: the Herfindahl Index, Theil�s Entropy, and a Transformed Herfindahl Index. The importance of method of concentration computation is included. In addition to market concentration, an intra-company concentration ratio is also included in the analysis. While no formal theory on this variable is provided, a positive regression b (using profits as a dependent variable) can be associated with specialization in that line. A negative b may be a sign of scope economies or even perhaps hedging strategies in portfolio underwriting. Section II provides invaluable articles that served as background to this analysis. Section III details the measurement and estimation methods. Section IV displays spatial analysis with ArcView. Section V presents summary statistics for the data. The remaining sections submit the results as well as directions for future research.
II. Background
Many studies have provided useful information on the structure and performance of the property and liability insurance industry. The following articles have been invaluable to this paper: Joskow (1973), Cummins and Weiss (1992), Mayers and Smith (1988), and Carroll (1993). Joskow generally reports that the property insurance industry possesses the characteristics of a competitive market. His analysis focuses on market concentration, economies of scale, and ease of entry. Joskow�s examination of the former is specifically applied to two individual lines of business: automobile and fire insurance. He also notes, however, that regulation and cartel pricing have discouraged price competition.
In their study, Cummins and Weiss appropriately extend the depth and breath of Joskow�s study to include most lines of insurance. The aim of their paper is to dispel the notion that insurance companies were responsible not only for premium inflation throughout the eighties but also the 1984-85 liability crisis. They echo Joskow�s conclusion that the property-liability insurance industry is competitively structured, yet thoroughly delineate the problems that have beleaguered the property-liability insurance industry. Some of these problems include: the availability and affordability of automobile insurance, the underwriting cycle, inappropriate profitability measures, rate regulation focus, and solvency requirements. While it could serve as an asset to the insurance industry, historically, regulation has focused on the wrong aspect of the industry.
Mayers and Smith use specialization and line of business concentration to examine the impact of major ownership structures of the property and casualty insurance industry. They report that Lloyds and reciprocals are more concentrated by line-of-business than stocks. When controlling for size, however, stocks are not only indistinguishable from mutuals, but appear also more concentrated than Lloyds. They mirror Joskow and Cummins and Weiss in that regulation may be an important determinant of variation.
The fourth study, by Carroll, provides a detailed analysis of the private workers� compensation market. While controlling for economic variables, she uses concentration (Herfindahl), regulation, and ease of entry to attempt to support her collusion and differential hypotheses. While she is not able to support either of these, she provides great insight in the use of her control variables.
The purpose of this paper is to provide an analysis of the Private and Commercial Auto Liability lines of business in the same spirit as the Carroll paper. A few additions have been included. First, the analysis to follow will scrutinize the choice of variable used to measure market concentration. Second, I include an intra-concentration index as an explanatory variable to the regression equation. The data is provided by BEST�s Aggregate Experience by State by Line from 1982 to 1992.
III. Measurement and Estimation Methods
Profitability
A simple measure of profitability can be computed as:
The compliment of the combined ratio, or the underwriting profit ratio, would present a better measure as it takes other expenses into account:
(Cummins and Tennyson 1992). Better still, would be the Overall Operating Ratio, one that also includes investment income. Ideally, however, profitability should include premiums, investment income, expenses, and the present value of losses. The stipulation of analysis and use of BEST�s Aggregate Data requires the allocation of investment income and expenses on a by-line basis (as insurers tend to write more than one line within a state). Rather than establishing the most suitable allocation measure, profitability is measured as follows:
and investments, expenses, and loss development is proxied (similarly to Carroll (1993)). The profit variable will simply be denoted as PROFIT.
First, to pick up the effect of investment income on profitability, the yearly Treasury bill return will be used to capture changes in interest rate (TBILL). These rates were obtained from The Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) asbbi file. Second, the ratio of unpaid losses to incurred losses will be used to capture the payout pattern (TAIL). By definition, the longer the payout tail, the greater the proportion of losses yet to be paid. Third, as suggested by Carroll, the direct writers� share of the market within each state serves as a proxy for expenses (DW). Cummins and VanDerhei (1978) reported that direct writers are more efficient than independent agency writers. Carroll�s main argument for the use of this variable is that it may capture the average demand for product quality.
Market Concentration
In the industrial organization literature, many indexes have been utilized to summarize the concentration of market shares as a single index. The most popular ones are the Gini coefficient (for examples see Sastry and Kelkar (1994), Lerman and Yitzhaki (1984), Shalit (1985)), the m-firm concentration ratio (for an example see Golan and Judge (1996), Theil�s Entropy (for examples see Van Hove (1993), Nissan (1996)), and, of course, the Herfindahl Index.
Figure 1: The Lorenz Curve for Market Share
Figure One illustrates a Lorenz Curve on the basis of market share. Segment [OF] defines function g (x)=x on the (0,1) domain. The Lorenz curve C(x) must be strictly and continuously increasing on (0,1). It�s boundary restrictions are C(0)=0 and C(1)=1. For each Lorenz Curve, we associate a Gini Coefficient, denoted by g and defined as:
It can easily be shown that g e (0,1) and that while Lerman and Yitzhaki (1984) and Shalit (1985) suggest algorithms for the computation of this integral, its evaluation is computationally cumbersome. Therefore, this measure is not considered in this paper.
The second market concentration variable, the m-firm concentration ratio, simply sums the m highest shares in the industry:
Golan and Judge (1996) find that if only one measure is used in estimating the distribution of the market shares, the Herfindahl Index provides a more effective method of estimation than the m-firm concentration ratio. Thus, the popular Herfindahl Index is the first concentration measure considered in this analysis. It is straightforwardly computed as the sum of the squares of the market shares:
Theil�s Entropy index is computed as the sum of the shares times their logarithm:
Hannah and Kay, using United Kingdom experience, have found the entropy index to be one of the most satisfactory (as the Herfindahl gives relatively too much weight to large size firms). As a result, the Herfindahl and Theil�s Entropy encompasses two of the three measures evaluated in this study. Figure One graphs the Herfindahl and Entropy measures on market share.
Precautions must be taken when analyzing the nature of the Entropy index. First, it is important to note that the Entropy index satiates around .36 (computed as a* in the figure). The Entropy index gives relatively more weight to smaller firms. Past a*=.36, the greater the company, the smaller the weight it will receive. It is, therefore, necessary to take note of the data set�s impact on this variable. Second, care must be taken in the computation of the a �s, the market shares. Attaran and Saghafi (1988) reported entropy indexes for the US manufacturing sector during the 1970-1984 period. Their conclusions rely on truncated entropy indexes that cover only the 500 largest firms in each year. In a series of replies, O�Neill (1993) shows of a truncated Entropy Index can lead to inaccurate values if the 500 firms are used as the "total market" of manufacturing firms. Using correct values of the Entropy index, O�Neill (1991) shows that Attaran and Saghafi�s results are actually reversed. Last, it must be stressed that a low Entropy Index is a measure of high concentration (see Table 1 below).
Table 1
Theoretical Market Number 1 |
Theoretical Market Number 2 |
||||||
Number of Companies |
Market |
Number of Companies |
Market |
||||
Share |
Entropy |
Herfindahl |
Share |
Entropy |
Herfindahl |
||
1 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
1 |
50.0% |
0.346574 |
0.25 |
2 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
2 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
3 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
3 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
4 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
4 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
5 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
5 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
6 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
6 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
7 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
7 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
8 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
8 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
9 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
9 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
10 |
10.0% |
0.2303 |
0.01 |
10 |
5.6% |
0.160576 |
0.00 |
Theil's Entropy: |
2.3026 |
Theil's Entropy: |
1.791759 |
||||
Herfindahl (*10,000): |
1,000 |
Herfindahl (*10,000): |
2,778 |
Koller and Weiss (1989) have also expressed the aforementioned premonition regarding the Herfindahl index in that it assigns a relatively great weight to large size companies. A Transformed Herfindahl is accordingly considered as the square root of the Herfindahl Index:
Theil�s Entropy, the Herfindahl, and the Transformed Herfindahl are computed on the basis of direct premiums written. These measures will be denoted as ENTROPY, HERF, and TRHERF respectively. Only firms with positive direct written premiums are considered in the computations of these variables. This is necessary not only to avoid violations of the logarithmic functions but also to render both Herfindahl measures sensible. Each will be compared in this framework.
Intra Company Concentration
The central focus of this paper is the intra-company concentration ratio. It is a Herfindahl-like concentration measure, simply computed as
I have failed to find previous articles dealing on the subject. No specific theory is introduced for this variable. A positive regression b could be associated with specialization within the line of business. A negative regression b , on the other hand, could be interpreted as the presence of risk diversification between lines and/or the presence scope economies. It is important to note that with the data available, it is impossible to discern between the two. While many articles have failed to find such scope economies in the Insurance Industry (for example see Hanweck and Hogan (1996), Grace and Timme (1992)), the intra-concentration ratio provides a different framework.
Market Code
As previously mentioned, Cummins and VanDerhei (1978) have found that direct writers have lower costs than independent writers. This finding, however, was coupled with the result that the inefficiencies of the independent agent seem not to be associated with loss adjustment factors, but rather from marketing and administrative expenses. Performing separate regressions for direct writers and agencies should make no difference as only premiums earned and losses incurred are taken into account in our profit measure.
Regulation
While the impact of rate regulation is hard to predict, it must be included in my analysis. The variable measuring rate regulation in each state is a dummy variable that is given a value of one if rates are restrictively regulated, and zero if rates are not. This data is only available through 1992 and therefore disables us from using a more recent information base. Furthermore, no regulation information is available for Alabama, the District of Columbia, Georgia, and Nebraska.
IV. Spatial Analysis
Auto Liability Insurance is divided into two branches: Private Auto and Commercial Auto. Figure 3 displays Private Auto Liability Market Concentration for 1982. As we stated in the introduction, traditional economic theory dictates that concentration facilitates collusion between firms and increases industry profitability. The Herfindahl Index was used to determine the degree of concentration of the auto liability insurance market. The states showing the highest market concentration are Washington, Oregon, New Mexico, Oklahoma, Kansas, Wisconsin, Ohio, Kentucky, Maine, Maryland and Missouri.
Figure 3: Private Auto Liability Concentration for 1982.
Regulation tends to increase concentration; the states that exhibit the highest market concentration in Commercial Auto Liability Market Concentration in 1992 (figure 4) are all state regulated: Washington, Oregon, California, Arizona, Texas, Kansas, Missouri, Florida, Georgia, North Carolina, Indiana, and New York. Two states, Colorado and Illinois reveal a high concentration but are not regulated. The four states showing the lowest concentration North Dakota, Mississippi, Alaska and Hawaii, are all state regulated. For these states, state regulation doesn't seem to have induced concentration.
Figure 4: Commercial Auto Regulation and Market Concentration 1992
The highest values of the Herfindahl index (our measure of concentration) are generally observed in the same regions as in figure 4 although the index values are often higher than that of Commercial Auto Liability Market Concentration. These regions are the West Coast, the central states from North Dakota to Oklahoma, and most of the states along the East Coast.
Figure 5: Private Auto Regulation and Market Concentration 1992.
In figure 6, Texas, Louisiana, Oklahoma, Kansas, Colorado, Wyoming and Alaska are experiencing a decrease in concentration. Washington, Nevada, Arizona, South Dakota, Indiana, Vermont, Tennessee, North and South Carolina, Georgia and Arkansas have increased their concentration between 1982 and 1992.
Figure 6: States With Extreme Change in Commercial Auto Liability (Adjusted for 1982 Dollars)
When one compares figure 6 to figure 7, one observes that there are only two states showing a decrease for private and commercial liability insurance: Wyoming and Kansas. Four states are showing an increase on both figures: Washington, Nevada, Arizona, and Arkansas. Texas, Florida, North Carolina, Kentucky, Maine, Alaska, and Hawaii are displaying an increase in Private Auto Liability.
Figure 7: States With Extreme Change in Private Auto Liability
As the number of firms in a market increases, so does competition. An increase in competition, in turn, may lead to a decrease in price and therefore to decrease profits. Figure 8 examines the Commercial Auto Liability Profit and Market Concentration for 1982. There were only two states displaying a profit: North Dakota and Kansas. The states with the highest concentration were Mississippi, Massachussets, Idaho, Montana, Nebraska, and West Virginia.
Figure 8: Commercial Auto Liability Profit and Market Concentration for 1982.
In addition to market concentration, an intra-company concentration ratio is also included in the analysis. For more detail, please consult part two.
The states displaying the highest intra firm market concentration for 1992 are California, Texas, Illinois, and New York. The highest profits are observed in Washington, Oregon, New Mexico, Oklahoma, Kansas, Iowa, Missouri, Wisconsin, Kentucky, Maryland, and Maine. Texas and California stand out for the highest private auto liability profit in 1992.
Figure 9: Private Auto Liability Profit and Intra Firm Market Concentration for 1992.
V. Regression and Data Summary
The following regression equation is estimated for the Private and Commercial Auto Liability lines of
Business in SAS on transformed data (around state means):
The analysis covers 1982 through 1992 and includes 47 States. Table 2A summarizes the regression variables. Table 2B and 2C provide summary of the Herfindahl for the Private Auto and Commercial Auto lines respectively.
Table 2A - Auto Liability Summary Statistics |
||||
Variable |
Private |
Commercial |
||
Mean |
Std Dev. |
Mean |
Std Dev. |
|
FREQUENCY |
87,226 |
87,226 |
102,493 |
102,493 |
DUMMY |
0.54721 |
0.49777 |
0.56843 |
0.49530 |
PREMIUM |
4,369,708 |
26,157,026 |
985,154 |
3,207,179 |
LOSS |
3,491,061 |
20,836,746 |
774,951 |
2,680,000 |
PROFIT |
0.20108 |
0.42386 |
0.21337 |
0.35688 |
DW |
0.62291 |
0.10977 |
0.19826 |
0.04795 |
TBILL |
0.07354 |
0.01979 |
0.07311 |
0.02002 |
ENT |
3.46869 |
0.26792 |
4.26410 |
0.32283 |
HERF |
0.07597 |
0.02091 |
0.02628 |
0.01208 |
THERF |
0.27306 |
0.03760 |
0.15868 |
0.03316 |
INTRA |
0.06493 |
0.09419 |
0.05952 |
0.09210 |
V. Results
The results were tabulated into two segments. The first three provide analysis of variances and parameter estimates for the Herfindahl, Entropy, and Transformed Herfindahl respectively (using the aforementioned regression equation). The most striking aspect of the regression results in these tables is that the variable TAIL is significant at the 1% level in all but one regression. This is actually not surprising as direct losses incurred figures in both the profit and tail measures. The second three provide the same summary statistics when TAIL is not included in the regression equation. Only the tables with the Herfindahl Index (Commercial and Private) are included.
Commercial Auto Liability |
|||||
Analysis of Variance |
|||||
Source |
Degrees of Freedom |
Sum of Squares |
Mean Square |
F Value |
Prob>F |
Model |
5 |
4.44174 |
0.88835 |
43.953 |
0.0001 |
Error |
511 |
10.32798 |
0.02021 |
||
C Total |
516 |
14.76972 |
|||
Root MSE |
0.14217 |
R-Square |
0.3007 |
||
Dep Mean |
0.19567 |
Adjusted R |
0.2939 |
||
C.V. |
72.65725 |
||||
Parameter Estimates |
|||||
Variable |
Parameter Estimate |
Standard Error |
T Stat (for t=0) |
Prob > |T| |
|
INTERCEPT |
0.64297 |
0.05063 |
12.7 |
0.0001 |
|
HERF |
-0.45694 |
0.50032 |
-0.913 |
0.3615 |
|
DW |
-0.24050 |
0.12701 |
-1.894 |
0.0589 |
|
TBILL |
-4.49444 |
0.31899 |
-14.09 |
0.0001 |
|
INTRA |
-0.54520 |
0.46588 |
-1.17 |
0.2424 |
|
DUMMY |
-0.04935 |
0.01362 |
-3.622 |
0.0003 |
|
Significant at the 1% Level |
Significant at the 5% Level |
Private Auto Liability |
|||||
Analysis of Variance |
|||||
Source |
Degrees of Freedom |
Sum of Squares |
Mean Square |
F Value |
Prob>F |
Model |
5 |
0.11304 |
0.02261 |
2.735 |
0.0189 |
Error |
511 |
4.22409 |
0.00827 |
||
C Total |
516 |
4.33713 |
|||
Root MSE |
0.09092 |
R-Square |
0.0261 |
||
Dep Mean |
0.19231 |
Adjusted R |
0.0165 |
||
C.V. |
47.27867 |
||||
Parameter Estimates |
|||||
Variable |
Parameter Estimate |
Standard Error |
T Stat (for t=0) |
Prob > |T| |
|
INTERCEPT |
0.15916 |
0.03191 |
4.988 |
0.0001 |
|
HERF |
-0.30210 |
0.23196 |
-1.302 |
0.1934 |
|
DW |
0.01034 |
0.04561 |
0.227 |
0.8207 |
|
TBILL |
0.38086 |
0.20600 |
1.849 |
0.0651 |
|
INTRA |
0.51066 |
0.22546 |
2.265 |
0.0239 |
|
DUMMY |
-0.01624 |
0.00828 |
-1.961 |
0.0504 |
|
Significant at the 1% Level |
Significant at the 5% Level |
The second surprising result is the great disparity in not only R2 measures, but also in parameter estimates when comparing the private and commercial Lines. First, in each equation, the model is notably more explanatory in the commercial lines, with R2 reaching as high as .40. Second, while market concentration and regulation estimates carry the same, sign every other parameter contrast when comparing the two lines.
In the commercial line, the INTRA-concentration is negative and mostly insignificant. This would tend away from specialization. The TBILL coefficient is negative and highly significant. This is consistent with the Cummins and Harrington result that price-cost margins are inversely related to the level of interest rates. The negative DW can be interpreted as counter evidence that direct writers earn higher profits than independent agents. When TAIL is included in the model, the sign of DW switches, but is still insignificant. Regulation DUMMY is negative and significant at the 1% level indicating that the presence of regulation in the market is associated with a decrease in profits. The HERF and THERF coefficients, while insignificant, are surprisingly negative (ENT positive) suggesting that decreases in concentration are actually associated with reduction in profits. Carroll obtained similar results on concentration. Comparison of market concentration measures is difficult in this line, as all coefficients are insignificant. The Herfindahl performed generally better than the other two.
In private line, the INTRA-concentration is positive and significant at the 5% level for all but one of the equations. This tends to favor specialization opportunities in this line. The TBILL and DW are positive, but not significantly so. As in the commercial line, the market concentration variables are also negative (positive entropy). In comparing the market concentration measures, the Entropy Index performed notably better than its counterparts, with p-values close to the 1% rejection area without TAIL and 5% with TAIL.
VI. Conclusion
Introducing the INTRA-concentration index provides an interesting twist to market performance and structure analysis. The difference in signs obtained when comparing the two auto liability lines may be inherent in the lines themselves. The negative (ENT significantly positive) market concentration in private auto liability may be partially explained by the ability of smaller companies to specialize in this line. Preliminary regressions involving an interaction of market and intra concentrations yielded positive and significant at the 5% level coefficients. This was not the case for the commercial line. Further research in this variable is needed.
Additional details could give rise to questions on the validity of the model: positive TBILL coefficient in the private line, negative DW in the commercial line, and relatively small private line R2. It must be noted that when regressing on individual data points, the signs of the coefficients are mostly preserved. Care, however, must be used when interpreting these results for the profit variable is simply computed as one minus the loss ratio. Adding market and administrative expenses, as well as investment income would make the variable much more representative of a true profit measure. Additionally, an evaluation of the loss payment pattern would include the volatility of the tail into the model. The ability to obtain these values would allow the amelioration of the model to a by state by line analysis.
References
Attaran, Mohsen and Massoud M. Saghafi, Nov 1988, "Concentration Trends and Profitability in the US Manufacturing Sector:1970-84", Applied Economics, 20(11): 1497-1510.
Bain, Joseph, 1951, "Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Manufacturing, 1936-1940", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 65:293-324.
Carroll, Anne M., 1993, "An Emprical Investigation of the Structure and Performance of the Private Workers� Compensation Market", The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 60, 2:185-207.
Cummins, J. David and Jack VanDerhei, 1979, "A Note on the Relative Efficiency of Property-Liability Insurance Distribution Systems, Bell Journal of Economics, 10: 709-715.
Cummins, J. David and Sharon Tennyson, 1992, "Controlling Automobile Insurance Costs, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6,2:95-115.
Cummins, J. David and Mary A. Weiss, 1992, "The Structure, Conduct and Regulation of the Property-Liability Insurance Industry", in: A. W. Kopcke and R. E. Randall, editions, The Financial Condition and Regulation of Insurance Companies, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.
Golan, Amos, Judge, George and Jeffrey M. Perloff, March 1996, "Estimating the Size Distribution of Firms Using Government Summary Statistics", Journal of Industrial Economics, 44(1): 69-80.
Grace, Martin and Stephen Timme, March 1992, "An Examination of Cost Economies in the United States Life Insurance Industry", Journal of Risk and Insurance, 72-103.
Hannah, L. and J.A. Kay, 1977, Concentration in Modern Industry: Theory , Measurement and the U.K. Eperience, The MacnMillian Press Ltd.
Hanweck, Gerald A. and Arthur M. B. Hogan, May 1996, "The Structure of the Property-Casualty Insurance Industry", Journal of Economics and Business, 48(2): 141-155.
Joskow, Paul L., 1973, "Cartels, Competition and Regulation in the Property-Liability Insurance Industry", Bell Journal of Economics, 4:375-427.
Koller, Roland H. and Leonard W. Weiss, 1989, "Price Levels and Seller Concentration: The Case of Portland Cement", in Concentration and Price, MIT Press.
Lerman, Robert I. and Yitzhaki, Shlomo, March 1995, "Changing ranks and the inequality impacts of taxes and transfers", National Tax Journal, 48(1): 45-59.
Love, James, Oct. 1986, "Commodity Concentration and Export Instability: The Choice of Concentration Measure and Analytical Framework", Journal of Developing Areas, 21(1): 63-73.
Mayers, David and Smith, C.W. Jr, 1988, "Ownership Structures Across Lines of Property-Casualty Insurance", Journal of Law and Economics, 31:371-378.
McGee, John S., 1971, In Defense of Industrial Concentration, Praeger Publishers.
Nissan, Edward, 1996, "Concentration in American Property-Casualty Companies",Journal of Actuarial Practice, 4,1: 131-142.
O'Neill, Patrick B., Jul 1991, "Measuring Relative Concentration of Sales in U.S. Manufacturing", Southern Economic Journal, 58(1): 263-267.
O'Neill, Patrick B. Saghafi, Massoud M. and Mohsen Attaran, Apr 1991, "Concentration Trends and Profitability in US Manufacturing: A Comment; A Reply and Some New Evidence, Applied Economics, 23(4B): 717-722.
O�Neill, Patrick B., Oct. 1993, "Concentration trends and profitability in US manufacturing: A further comment and some new (and improved) evidence, Applied Economics, 25(10): 1285-1286.
Palepu, Krishna, 1985, "Diversification Strategy, Profit Performance and the Entropy Measure", Strategic Management Journal, 6(3): 239-255.
Sastry, D. and Ujwala R. Keljar, Aug. 1994, "Note on the decomposition of Gini inequality", Review of Economics & Statistics,76(3): 584-586.
Scherer, F., 1980, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Second Edition, Chicago: Rand-McNally.
Shalit, Haim, May 1985, "Calculating the Gini Index of Inequality of Individual Data, Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics, 47(2): 185-189.
Stigler, G. J., 1964, "A Theory of Oligopoly", The Journal of Political Economy, 72: 44-61.
van Hove, Leo, Oct. 1993, "Diversification of primary energy consumption in six West European countries", Energy Economics, 15(4): 239-244.